Papers
Topics
Authors
Recent
Detailed Answer
Quick Answer
Concise responses based on abstracts only
Detailed Answer
Well-researched responses based on abstracts and relevant paper content.
Custom Instructions Pro
Preferences or requirements that you'd like Emergent Mind to consider when generating responses
Gemini 2.5 Flash
Gemini 2.5 Flash 48 tok/s
Gemini 2.5 Pro 48 tok/s Pro
GPT-5 Medium 26 tok/s Pro
GPT-5 High 19 tok/s Pro
GPT-4o 107 tok/s Pro
Kimi K2 205 tok/s Pro
GPT OSS 120B 473 tok/s Pro
Claude Sonnet 4 37 tok/s Pro
2000 character limit reached

New Results for the $k$-Secretary Problem (2012.00488v1)

Published 1 Dec 2020 in cs.DS

Abstract: Suppose that $n$ items arrive online in random order and the goal is to select $k$ of them such that the expected sum of the selected items is maximized. The decision for any item is irrevocable and must be made on arrival without knowing future items. This problem is known as the $k$-secretary problem, which includes the classical secretary problem with the special case $k=1$. It is well-known that the latter problem can be solved by a simple algorithm of competitive ratio $1/e$ which is optimal for $n \to \infty$. Existing algorithms beating the threshold of $1/e$ either rely on involved selection policies already for $k=2$, or assume that $k$ is large. In this paper we present results for the $k$-secretary problem, considering the interesting and relevant case that $k$ is small. We focus on simple selection algorithms, accompanied by combinatorial analyses. As a main contribution we propose a natural deterministic algorithm designed to have competitive ratios strictly greater than $1/e$ for small $k \geq 2$. This algorithm is hardly more complex than the elegant strategy for the classical secretary problem, optimal for $k=1$, and works for all $k \geq 1$. We derive its competitive ratios for $k \leq 100$, ranging from $0.41$ for $k=2$ to $0.75$ for $k=100$. Moreover, we consider an algorithm proposed earlier in the literature, for which no rigorous analysis is known. We show that its competitive ratio is $0.4168$ for $k=2$, implying that the previous analysis was not tight. Our analysis reveals a surprising combinatorial property of this algorithm, which might be helpful to find a tight analysis for all $k$.

Citations (18)

Summary

We haven't generated a summary for this paper yet.

List To Do Tasks Checklist Streamline Icon: https://streamlinehq.com

Collections

Sign up for free to add this paper to one or more collections.

Lightbulb On Streamline Icon: https://streamlinehq.com

Continue Learning

We haven't generated follow-up questions for this paper yet.